Categories
Economics Politics & government

[2951] Politics of prices is counter-productive

There has been a global supply constraint of various kinds for at least a year now. The supply chain disruption was expected by many—I quickly noted the post-war Malayan supply-side crisis as a parallel. Nevertheless, few people expected the constraints would be this tight for so long. I certainly did not.

The tightness has slipped over into the Malaysian consumer market. Chicken, beef, vegetables are the usual suspects.

The waitlists for cars are long due to a persistent global chip shortage: I test drove a Peugeot several weeks back and that experience to me underscores how modern ground vehicles these days are more and more an electronic device than a mechanical one. I knew vehicles had an ever increasing electronics (and electrical) components to them. Several months earlier, I read a report showing how the share of electronic cost relative to total car manufacturing cost has gone up drastically in the past 20 years, from less than 1% to maybe 40%-60%. But there is a difference between reading it, and riding the thing. The dashboard is a computer screen popping more information any older car could show. When I say dashboard, I mean a dashboard full of dynamic data, with customizable menu. The air-conditioning controls are only accessible through a separate central LCD screen, which also controls other aspects of the car. Even the brakes can be controlled by the computer, along with so many other things.

It is not just chip and electronic components are in short supply. Somebody on Twitter jokingly said “oh, this is the chip shortages they were talking about” in reference to shortages of fries at McDonald’s in Malaysia and Japan.

Consumer prices are rising, and it would have risen higher if it was not for price control mechanism and subsidies in place in Malaysia. This is readily observed from the following chart, where consumer prices are not rising as fast as producer prices. The latter is a proxy to global prices.

PPI vs CPI

Nevertheless, despite enjoying the shield, consumers have been complaining about rising living costs. They demand actions. More than a few activists and politicians have demanded the same.

All governments are sensitive to such criticisms and this government, especially as weak, incompetent and clueless as it is, is doubly so. The opposition has been relentless in their criticism. Some Pakatan Harapan supporters have highlighted how their government played a better and proactive role in addressing prices, and go on to claim a Pakatan Harapan government would have been far more effective in managing cost of living problem. And when Pakatan Harapan was in power, Barisan Nasional and Pas, on top of their usual racist rhetoric, also attacked the government for rising living costs regardless of whether prices was actually rising (prices then were actually very stable due to the imposition of an overly generous blanket fuel subsidy).

I dislike politics of prices. While it has its uses in cases when there are monopoly abuses and regulatory hurdles (the drop in broadband prices are a great exception), in the current climate prices are largely out of the government hands. The truth is, if Pakatan Harapan was in power, they too would not be able to do much about it either.

But that does not matter. Such is the politics of prices.

The problem is with the supply itself and the players of politics of prices simply ignore the cause of the problem. Some even go has far as misdiagnosing it as unhelpfully as greed.

A supply-driven crisis like this requires investment to loosen up the supply chain: expansion of ports, new technology to hasten production and delivery, new plants, more workers, etc. Yet, the aversion for price hikes have led to large government subsidies (think fuel), which takes fund away from productive investment purposes that are needed to address the supply chain disruption.

Politics of prices not only ignore the source of price pressures Malaysian consumers are experiencing. They ignore wages. Prices and wages are part of the same coin: wages are prices of labor. Notwithstanding issues relating to income distribution between employees and employers, and technology-driven price cuts among others, the politics of prices suppresses price growth, and through it, risk of suppressing wage growth.

More than once, the politics of prices have led to calls for wage cuts. The targets have been high-paying professionals and ministers (and their unqualified advisors), but too often, it has gone a little bit too far. Mahathir as the 7th Prime Minister for instance, is a fan of pay cuts and that unfortunately set the tone for the whole economy when he was in power. Coupled with his obsession with government debt (government debt and transparency were a problem), and his history with the gold dinar movement, it felt like he wanted a deflationary environment.

All that set the tone for austerity. There was really no austerity in place—government spending went up and the economy expanded—but the narrative set by the PM made it difficult to convince many out there that that was no austerity. And the economy, even as it expanded, took heed of the deflationary sentiment.

Categories
Economics

[2861] The society (and the GDP) is larger than a collection of individuals

It is fashionable in certain circles these days in Malaysia to question the reliability of GDP as a measure of welfare. They say they do not feel GDP growth and they prefer something like household income or wage statistics to a measure that is hard to understand. The more extreme criticism goes to claim GDP is worthless.

A journalist recently called me up for a crash course in GDP, just after the release of the third quarter statistics. “Why would the GDP matter to the man on the streets?” She asked me in a combative tone, as if I was lying about GDP, as if I was part of a conspiratorial system.

But GDP has functions that wages and household income cannot fulfill, just as wages and household income play roles GDP cannot properly fit in.

Wages and household income describe individualized statistics. Its appeal to personal welfare is also its weakness: it does not describe much beyond the individuals.

If the world were all about the individuals and the things happening within the four walls of our homes, then wages and household income would be sufficient. But there are entities that exist outside that do not contribute to our incomes and wages directly. And yet, those extra-household activities bring benefits to us (and sometimes, not so).

For instance, if a robot owned collectively by a community of humans provides a service to the neighborhood for a nominal fee (or perhaps even at market price), and that the robot income is used for community improvement instead of being paid as dividend to individuals, it is not clear to me wages and household income would increase as a result. But that income would definitely be counted under GDP.

Or if you are a Luddite and dislike the example, consider a more traditional case. If a government-run business — like operating the trains — makes profit and pays dividend to public coffers while the government itself is running a fiscal surplus, that income would not translate into wages or household income. But GDP would take care of that income, taking it as income for the whole economy.

Granted, GDP has its issues but we have to be careful about making false dichotomy when in truth GDP, wages and household income (along with other statistics) play complementary roles within multiple contexts. There are times GDP is more useful than wage stats and there are times the reverse is true. A widening productivity-wage gap, for instance, can be worrying within the current system and headline GDP figures might not be as illuminating as wage/household income statistics. And there are times all are useful. A complete picture of the world would use all measures available.

To kick GDP out as worthless in favor of a more restrictive statistics centered purely on the individuals is to develop a worldview of selfishness, that the world is all about me, me and me while discarding the fact we live in a society. The society can be larger than a collection of individuals. And I say that as a libertarian.

Categories
Economics

[2529] Malaysian household income evolution by ethnicity, 1970-2009

There are a lot of conversations about income these days. In Malaysia, the conversations also get a bit racial sometimes. But how did it look like over the past years?

The following describes the average Malaysian household monthly income (pre-tax) according to ethnicity:

This is in nominal ringgit, i.e. it does not account for inflation.

I believe this (the total series) should be read with my entry on 2010 average household expenditure (which states that average nominal expenditure was RM2,200) and the 1999 average household expenditure according to income class. That is especially so to clear up the disagreement about saving and investment that was brought up in the comment section of the former entry,  i.e. expenditure does not equal income and that means saving or investment activities are not included as part of expenditure. As you can see, 2010 expenditure for an average Malaysian household was about RM2,200. Compare that to the 2009 income, which was RM4,000. The more or less RM1,800 difference between the expenditure and income is likely either saving or investment.

Categories
Economics

[2526] Improve real wages by liberalizing the auto industry

The articulation of concern for stagnating wages is well-rehearsed among Malaysians who are just entering the labor force as well as those earning low wages. For most fresh graduates especially, life in the city would be far more painful than it is without the support of their parents.

Regardless of justification, many have complained about rising prices and their disappointing wage levels and growth. While from a strict economic perspective it is arguable that the complaints about inflation are largely exaggerated, based on cherry-picking reasoning and frequently are based on conceptual misunderstanding of inflation, real wages is still an issue. The issue is that it has not been growing as fast as many would like it to, nor do they match their qualifications and capability. The brain-drain phenomenon is partly caused by the concern for wages as well.

PEMANDU targets to double the per capita income of Malaysians in a certain timeframe. Notwithstanding the argument that the target will be achieved even without PEMANDU and that the doubling of income per capita is really more inflationary than real, the target and the relevant plans highlight how wage growth is a pillar of the Najib administration’s policy.

What truly matters is real income. The series of criticism and counter-criticism between REFSA and PEMANDU at least suggests that beyond technicalities that will get policy wonks excited, hostile political maneuvering and a superficial public relations exercise, both organizations are concerned with real income. That is good. That means the mainstream debate is on the right track and the competitive public political sphere to some extent is working.

But even taking the target by PEMANDU in good faith, the plan is overly intricate. For a grand plan that is supposed to be driven by the private sector, it should not be too complicated. If it were privately driven, then the planning should be left to the market’s thousands of private planners working in the go-go economic center that is Kuala Lumpur, not left to central planners working in government complexes in the desolated, isolated and pretentious Putrajaya.

Granted, the PEMANDU plans are a set of national economic policies. Some complexity is inevitable but the truth is that this is a government-driven plan. And it overlooks simple and quick market-based solutions.

One of those policies is the liberalization of the automotive industry.

Prices of cars are amazingly high in Malaysia. This reality is amazing given that fact that cars are easily tradable and Malaysia has one of the most open and trade-dependent economies in the world. The characteristic of tradability and open market should make motor vehicles reasonably affordable. Yet, most cars in Malaysia are overly expensive in general. It takes so much out of a person’s income to own what is a considered a necessity.

The reason for this is protectionism. The industry suffers from punitive taxes and duties all aimed at giving domestic car producers a leg up. Competitive pressure is prevented from pushing prices of both local and foreign cars down to more reasonable and affordable levels. The same competitive pressure has the potential of pushing the prices of even the cheapest cars in Malaysia down.

While this particular liberalization policy does not increase wages, it does improve real wages significantly because the servicing of a car loan can be a major household expenditure. With less restrictive taxes and duties, this particular chunk of household expenditure will decrease, hence improving the household’s real income. More importantly, instead of dedicating a large fraction of income to servicing car loans, newly freed income can be used to purchase other goods, services or simply saved. To put it simply, they can do more with less.

The attractiveness of the liberalization is not just about improved real income. It is also about improving real income almost immediately. Contrast this to the intricate plan to double the headline wages of Malaysians by year 2020 by propping up small inefficient sundry shops when large retailers can do the job much better due to their economies of scale. This begs the question, why should Malaysia do this the hard, expensive, incentive-twisting way when there are quicker, simpler and more organic solutions?

There are other considerations of course, like the fate of those employed in that particular inefficient local industry.

It is true that there will always be winners and losers but the comeback point is that there will be more winners than losers: the losers are concentrated in a particular industry which is small relative to the whole economy to start with, and the winners are widely dispersed throughout the economy on a much larger scale. On top of that, the newly unused income will create new permanent demand that will likely be able to absorb the temporary disruption in the labor market and redirect resources, both labor and capital, to better use, all without too much overbearing government intervention.

Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved
First published in The Malaysian Insider on March 23 2012.

Categories
ASEAN Economics

[2018] Of with ceasation of supply, protectionist will be proven wrong

Wages in Malaysia are generally depressed.

Protectionists blame foreign labor as the main cause of that depression. According to them, if we are less dependent on foreign labor — low-skilled mostly — wages will go up. So, they want to kick out as many foreign labor as possible. Even all, for the extremists.

They make that assertion without considering foreign labor are active in sectors mostly different from the ones locals are participating in; there simply not enough locals wanting to participate in the sectors filled with foreign labor.

Removal of these foreigners will no doubt increase wages up as the law of supply and demand demands it, but that is largely true only in those sectors. The problem of wage depression in the larger economy will not be addressed or significantly affected with the absence of foreign labor.

In front of our eyes is a natural experiment to prove that. Indonesia has decided to stop the flow of maid into Malaysia:

JAKARTA, June 25 (Bernama) – Beginning today, Indonesia will halt temporarily sending maids to Malaysia until there are discussions on the review of the memorandum of understanding (MoU) on the matter. [Indonesian Maids To Malaysia Halted Temporarily. Bernama. June 25 2009]

I am confident that while wages for maids will rise, wages in other sectors will remain largely unaffected.

In fact, Malaysian productivity might fall because Malaysians who face high opportunity cost between housework and professional job might not be able to do what Adam Smith wrote in The Wealth of Nations: specialization.

And in economics, besides supply and demand, productivity is a major component in the determination of wages.