Categories
Economics Politics & government

[2951] Politics of prices is counter-productive

There has been a global supply constraint of various kinds for at least a year now. The supply chain disruption was expected by many—I quickly noted the post-war Malayan supply-side crisis as a parallel. Nevertheless, few people expected the constraints would be this tight for so long. I certainly did not.

The tightness has slipped over into the Malaysian consumer market. Chicken, beef, vegetables are the usual suspects.

The waitlists for cars are long due to a persistent global chip shortage: I test drove a Peugeot several weeks back and that experience to me underscores how modern ground vehicles these days are more and more an electronic device than a mechanical one. I knew vehicles had an ever increasing electronics (and electrical) components to them. Several months earlier, I read a report showing how the share of electronic cost relative to total car manufacturing cost has gone up drastically in the past 20 years, from less than 1% to maybe 40%-60%. But there is a difference between reading it, and riding the thing. The dashboard is a computer screen popping more information any older car could show. When I say dashboard, I mean a dashboard full of dynamic data, with customizable menu. The air-conditioning controls are only accessible through a separate central LCD screen, which also controls other aspects of the car. Even the brakes can be controlled by the computer, along with so many other things.

It is not just chip and electronic components are in short supply. Somebody on Twitter jokingly said “oh, this is the chip shortages they were talking about” in reference to shortages of fries at McDonald’s in Malaysia and Japan.

Consumer prices are rising, and it would have risen higher if it was not for price control mechanism and subsidies in place in Malaysia. This is readily observed from the following chart, where consumer prices are not rising as fast as producer prices. The latter is a proxy to global prices.

PPI vs CPI

Nevertheless, despite enjoying the shield, consumers have been complaining about rising living costs. They demand actions. More than a few activists and politicians have demanded the same.

All governments are sensitive to such criticisms and this government, especially as weak, incompetent and clueless as it is, is doubly so. The opposition has been relentless in their criticism. Some Pakatan Harapan supporters have highlighted how their government played a better and proactive role in addressing prices, and go on to claim a Pakatan Harapan government would have been far more effective in managing cost of living problem. And when Pakatan Harapan was in power, Barisan Nasional and Pas, on top of their usual racist rhetoric, also attacked the government for rising living costs regardless of whether prices was actually rising (prices then were actually very stable due to the imposition of an overly generous blanket fuel subsidy).

I dislike politics of prices. While it has its uses in cases when there are monopoly abuses and regulatory hurdles (the drop in broadband prices are a great exception), in the current climate prices are largely out of the government hands. The truth is, if Pakatan Harapan was in power, they too would not be able to do much about it either.

But that does not matter. Such is the politics of prices.

The problem is with the supply itself and the players of politics of prices simply ignore the cause of the problem. Some even go has far as misdiagnosing it as unhelpfully as greed.

A supply-driven crisis like this requires investment to loosen up the supply chain: expansion of ports, new technology to hasten production and delivery, new plants, more workers, etc. Yet, the aversion for price hikes have led to large government subsidies (think fuel), which takes fund away from productive investment purposes that are needed to address the supply chain disruption.

Politics of prices not only ignore the source of price pressures Malaysian consumers are experiencing. They ignore wages. Prices and wages are part of the same coin: wages are prices of labor. Notwithstanding issues relating to income distribution between employees and employers, and technology-driven price cuts among others, the politics of prices suppresses price growth, and through it, risk of suppressing wage growth.

More than once, the politics of prices have led to calls for wage cuts. The targets have been high-paying professionals and ministers (and their unqualified advisors), but too often, it has gone a little bit too far. Mahathir as the 7th Prime Minister for instance, is a fan of pay cuts and that unfortunately set the tone for the whole economy when he was in power. Coupled with his obsession with government debt (government debt and transparency were a problem), and his history with the gold dinar movement, it felt like he wanted a deflationary environment.

All that set the tone for austerity. There was really no austerity in place—government spending went up and the economy expanded—but the narrative set by the PM made it difficult to convince many out there that that was no austerity. And the economy, even as it expanded, took heed of the deflationary sentiment.

Categories
Economics

[2912] Wisdom is knowing when prices failed

There are discussions — or rather venom exchanges as it goes on social media these days — about prices and price control of certain items. I think I am here to highlight the obvious because oftentimes the obvious is overlooked due to familiarity: prices are only a method of allocation out for many out there.

There are other various methods in our toolbox if we care to learn.

Prices as an efficient allocator of resources

Now, prices are usually the best (efficient) allocator of goods and services in a society under normal circumstances. The thing with prices is that it is a reflection of the underlying demand, supply, and the context those demand and supply. Prices encapsulate all the necessary information needed to allocate resources. And under normal circumstances, that is good enough to allocate resources efficiently.

“Normal circumstances” is a catch-all cheat phrase. It almost always includes the assumption of (near) competitive/efficient market. Efficiency needs to be defined further: net increase in societal welfare. If it leads to a net decrease, the efficiency argument would melt away, and so too the merit of prices. Never mind prices, in theory, are not the only way to clear the market.

I make it sounds as if the price assumptions are a set of flimsy conditions. They are not. They are quite robust and hard to break, really. More than that after the section immediately below. The point is, it takes an extraordinary circumstance for it to happen.

When prices failed

During a war for instance with staple items suffering from massive supply disruption, prices will shoot up to an astronomical level. It is unclear prices will be the best means of allocating resources in this case if it would lead to a majority dying out of hunger due to unaffordability instead of absence of food, or protection gears. Even more so when a panic strikes, and hoarding takes place. After all, prices are only a means to a end. We care a whole lot more than prices. We care about our welfare.

This is mainsteam economics: most people do learn about market failures, that is when market mechanism decreases societal net welfare due to private cost failing to account for public cost.

Augmenting prices

When prices failed, it does not mean prices as a whole failed. There are various designs available to counter such failure before prices become completely irrelevant to welfare concerns. We can do price discrimination for instance, even all the way to first degree if we have the technology. We can impose quota within price mechanism. We have taxes and subsidies, an even that could be handled through tax and subsidy discrimination. We can impose coupon within price mechanism for instance. There are price ceiling and floor. We can be creative within market mechanism.

Do not forget these truths: we know when market mechanism is superior, and when it is not. And there are degrees of failure. Do not let your politics blinds you to it.

Knowledge and wisdom

Knowledge is about knowing the tools of allocation available and all of its possible combinations. Wisdom is knowing which tool and its combinations are useful during which period. In the case of prices, wisdom is knowing instances of market failures and which tools are available to address it. Prices are not superior all the times. Remember its assumptions.

Now, we have a crisis on our hands and it is affecting some items in the market. Some items are more important than others. We have the tools. Perhaps we need to relearn our lesson and develop some wisdom.

This is especially so when we are so partial to a method of allocation that we forget the assumptions why it works in the first place. We cannot imagine that those assumptions can breakdown.

This failure of imagination is perhaps a flaw in our classrooms. We take for granted these assumptions for pedagogic reason at the entry level in economics classes. It is worse when it done thru rote learning. And these weaknesses form the basis of popeconomics that is sorely inadequate to address our supply-side crisis.

Categories
Economics Politics & government

[2745] We need to ration our water

There seems yet another water crisis on the horizon, or here even. But walking around, it is hard to know that for sure. Out there in the streets well out of the dams and water plants, building management are instructing their workers to water the grass even after the rain, keeping it green and all. I spotted one worker watering a tree with a huge trunk for several minutes, while reading his phone. Car owners are washing their cars with generous amount of water. AirAsia plans the largest water balloon fight in Malaysia in November this year, right in the middle of Petaling Jaya, somehow trivializing the water assets negotiation in Selangor. AirAsia calls it Burst Asia and tickets are selling for RM48.

Yet, from the news we are learning water at various dams are below the critical levels previously seen earlier this year when rationing took place. The authority is pumping water from old mining ponds into our water supply as a solution. There are accusations that the ponds are contaminated with heavy metals. Whether it is true or not, it is clear this is a sign of desperation with the authority trying to augment the dam water in Selangor. If that does not signal desperation, then the sudden turn of events in the past months with respect to the Selangor water assets negotiation has to be one. After all, the basis for the Pahang-Selangor water tunnel and the controversial Langat 2 water plant revolves around future water shortage. There are those who claim the current shortage is a made-up crisis, especially among those in the current Selangor state government. They claim sabotage, saying somebody is trying to make the state government look bad. I do not know about those saboteurs but there is a water crisis, regardless of its sources.

Water prices meanwhile remain cheap. It has not changed for some time now. The Selangor state government refuses to raise it, supposedly for the benefit of the people, claiming the water companies are not doing enough to warrant a tariff hike. While these water companies are indeed slacking off, breaching their contracts and there is even a smell of corruption in the air, prices remain low and controlled too tightly to encourage judicious use of water. The free water policy by Selangor also does not seem to help. Sure, the free water policy says water is free of charge up to a certain level but the idea of free and saving do not go along well with each other. The policy encourages consumption, not saving.

So, there is a water crisis on the supply side but it does not seem to be so, looking at the consumption side.

Why?

It is because information does not flow from supply to the demand side. Prices do not correspond with water supply and so consumers, whether residential, commercial or industrial, act normal. Prices are prevented from functioning properly.

To correct the situation, we need to float the prices, or at least hike it up. Unfortunately, there is no political will for that. In fact, the current political establishment is hostile to any hike. Selangor Menteri Besar Khalid Ibrahim has guaranteed there will be no rationing. And lest people make him a scapegoat, that is a Pakatan Rakyat’s policy. Their credibility is dependent on a no hike outcome.

Given that political constraint, the next best thing is to resort to non-market solutions. That involves water rationing unfortunately.

There has to be a signal sent to the demand side, telling these consumers, “hey guys, there is a water crisis here. You might want to slow it down a notch.” Without that signal, consumers will act as if everything is alright. If it goes as things are going, there might be none to ration at all later. So, we need to send a stronger signal to the consumers. News reports alone are not working.

I know several people have written in support of rationing. Add me into that list.

I do believe water users in Selangor and Kuala Lumpur will tolerate rationing better than having no water at all.