Categories
Conflict & disaster Economics

[2949] Misaligned powers, incentives between the federal regulator and state authorities contributed to the 2021 great Malaysian flooding

The government has blamed the recent flooding on once-in-a-hundred-years rainfall. Blames have been assigned to climate change too.

I have never experienced such prolonged rainfall before, and it was an extraordinary experience. Thankfully I did not have to suffer the flooding. Unfortunately, many others did and they were cursed with an incompetent government at the helm that was slow to realize the problem, and slow to act upon it. For a government so used to living the crisis-mode, one would expect they would have some kind of preparedness, or seasoned enough to lead a proper competent response. But no, it was a disastrous handing. Old clueless men and women, they are.

The Environment Minister himself back in October dismissed the talks of big floods, despite the prevailing La Nina phenomenon that brought increased rainfall across the Asia-Pacific region. His dismissal played a deplorable role of lowering down the greater population’s guard. There are several persons in government should be fired for incompetence and negligence—lives were lost, properties damaged—and that particular minister is high in the long list.

But the severe floods across Malaysia has happened much more often than once in a century. Kuala Lumpur alone has had its share of several bad floods. The big one in Kelantan that happened less than 10 years ago. Clearly, there is more to it than just once-in-a-hundred-years rainfall.

And excessive logging is one of those several contributing factors.

Specifically, here, I would like to highlight the regulatory environment relating to logging. The system is flawed and provides excessive incentives leading to widespread environmental disasters that makes the big flooding possible. Instead of remedying the problem of misaligned incentives, the system makes the tragedy of the commons worse.

The two-part systemic flaw

There are two major parts of the systemic flaw: the state controls the issuance of logging permit, while the federal authority leads the environmental policing part. To further complicates matter, the federal regulator regulates peninsular matters only.

The approving authority trumps federal authority due to the current constitutional arrangement, as provided under the Ninth Schedule of the Constitution of Malaysia. The extensive power of the state governments over the forest is further clarified in the National Forestry Act 1984. In short, the federal regulatory body is powerless in the face of state governments.

Furthermore, the state governments, particularly the poorer ones like Pahang, suffers from adverse incentives arising out of the lack of revenue. In Malaysia, tax revenue (income tax and consumption tax are the major ones) is mainly the purview of the federal government and not enough has been returned to the states from the federal level. This insufficient sharing is also a reflection of the low-tax regime Malaysia has: you cannot share if you do not have enough in the first place. It is also a reflection of partisan politics, as Kelantan and Terengganu suffered before.

Given the state’s lack of tax revenue, and insufficient revenue support from the federal government, the states have to resort to other means of generating revenue: among them include monetizing land and the forest. With the goal of supporting state government operations, excessive logging permits are issued.

(In Sabah and Sarawak where the regulator comes under state authority unlike in the 11 states in the Peninsular, arguably the pressure for revenue forces the government to prioritize harvesting over protection. For instance, Sabah recently lifted its state-wide ban on timber exports that was imposed in 2018).

Additionally, many of these states come under the influence of the royal houses, which demand a share of the forest resources. The state government more often than not, would comply. I have a short family history to share here to illustrate the problem of toothless regulation in the face of state rights. An uncle of mine decades ago used to be a forestry officer in a certain large state. He stopped a logging operation linked to the royal house of the state. He ended up being transferred out of the state. The logging operation continued.

Managing the commons

One way to address the flaw and manage the commons better is to take away the states authority over the forest, and have the federal government compensates the state government through large institutional sharing of tax revenue beyond what is provided currently through items like capitation grants. The downside is that, as you can guess it, higher tax burden for everybody on average.

Through this realignment of powers and incentives, the pressures of deforestation through logging could be removed, and the regulatory authority would have stronger powers to preserve the jungle. That will help lessen the chances of big floods recurring (with all else the same).

Categories
Conflict & disaster Economics

[2760] The deficit can wait

I have been supportive of the government’s attempt at closing the deficit. I do celebrate the significant fiscal progress made over the past five or six years.

In retrospect, it was easy to back the cuts because the times were generally good. After a recession in 2009, the Malaysian economy grew quite well almost every quarter and that made tough policies easier to swallow.

But times are changing and what was swallowed easily yesterday will be tough today. Those tough policies will be hard on almost everybody now if executed too religiously.

The situation has changed so fast that I feel almost nobody ”• at least as far as I can see in the financial market ”• still believes the original deficit target of 3.0 per cent to GDP for 2015 is credible anymore. It will be challenging to meet the target and if the government insists on meeting it anyway, something has to give and that something will be overall economic growth.

Growth here is not merely an economic figure appearing in someone’s spreadsheet. It is people’s livelihood which is at stake.

Partly in my effort to be pragmatic and partly from observing from afar the horrible European experience arising from the wrong timing of its austerity program, I have come to believe in having a counter-cyclical policy. We commit to tough reforms making the economy more efficient during the good times and then we give it a slack when things are not so sunny and cheery.

What I am saying here is that the government here in Malaysia should be flexible with its deficit target for the time being.

I sincerely believe we can afford to do so because we have done serious fiscal reforms recently. Petrol and diesel subsidies are no more after years of gradual cuts and we are finally implementing the goods and services tax after years of contemplating it. I think the long term trajectory from the initiatives has already set the right direction.

My only disappointment is that these reforms were not done sooner due to political concerns. Everybody was so concerned about their political prospect that they forgot or even ignored the country’s future. For months, the government went on autopilot and the subsidy cuts themselves were put on hold for quite some time as the government prepared for the 2013 general election. We lost valuable policy time and now the window is closing.

But what is done is done and perhaps, that is just the cost of maintaining a democracy, however flawed ours is. If we believe in countercyclical policy, we should now switch our focus from fiscal tightening to some kind of relaxation.

In fact, with this framework in mind we should target the deficit within an economic cycle instead of the Gregorian calendar and I think, again, with the reforms done, we should be able to close the gap in the long run.

And we ”• when I use the pronoun we here particularly, I mean the government; after all, we elected the government regardless whether we like those sitting in Putrajaya spending our money ”• do honestly have a legitimate requirement to spend this time around, which runs contrary to keeping the what seems to be an impossible deficit target to meet.

No, it is not about saving 1Malaysia Development Berhad ”• a beast which we will have to address ”• or paying thousands of ringgit for a set of screwdrivers, or even giving more free money to suspicious grantpreneurs and selecting winners in the economy. It is about helping fellow Malaysians.

Pictures of devastation from the recent floods are heartbreaking. As fellow citizens, it is our duty to lighten their burden and the government is our primary agent to do so. Not some political parties, not some NGOs, not some volunteers. It is good to see people helping out but our agent is the government. We pay taxes and we expect the government to provide the basic infrastructure that the country needs to go forward. It is the basic role of a government.

These infrastructures from water to bridges to schools in the east coast need repairs. We need to spend for the repairs and in many cases, for reconstruction altogether.

That spending would probably hit the deficit figures but it is for a good cause. The deficit can wait for another day.

Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved
First published in The Malay Mail on January 17 2015.

Categories
Conflict & disaster Politics & government

[1042] Of itu banjir…

Today in the New Straits Times:

Fair use. Scanned from NST January 8 2007 by Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams.

Ouch!

The Malay term itu banjir means “that is a flood”.

If the joke is lost on you, see an entry on Eye on Malaysia and another one on what the Prime Minister did during a national disaster for some background.

Heck. Just go and read Bakri Musa’s.

Categories
Environment

[1028] Of 2006 top Malaysian environmental issues

With a little over 24 hours before 2006 comes to a close, let us revisit all the green issues mentioned in two other entries — entry [775] and [879]:

  1. Smelly tap water in the Klang Valley in February. Not just smelly, it smelled like shit. The smell was caused by ammonia released from several improperly managed landfills. The landfills later were shut down, at least, according to reports. See [756].
  2. The tabling of the Water Services Industry Bill in April. Proposed death penalty to polluters. See [765].
  3. With the shut down of landfills, a related problem ensued: shortage of landfills in April too. See [775].
  4. Big flood in the northern states early in the year. See [775].
  5. Flash flood in Shah Alam. Local residents were positively angry. See [775].
  6. Deforestation in various states. TV3 played an active role in informing the public. See [709] and [720].
  7. The Malaysian Nature Society’s Save Belum-Temengor campaign. See [885]
  8. The drive towards biofuel. See [775].
  9. Proposed mega palm oil estate by Indonesia on Borneo. It affects Malaysia because, well, it would be on the border. See [775].
  10. Proposed nuclear energy for Malaysia. See [775].
  11. Bird flu. See [775].
  12. Landslide at Genting Highlands. See [775].
  13. Damage to Sipadan coral reef in May. The accident forced the Sabah state government to halt construction of a huge facility at Sipadan after coming under attack from the public. See [791].
  14. Metal smelter in Bakun. See [879].
  15. Cancellation of Broga incinerator. See [879].
  16. Haze. And yeah, I told you so. See [879].
  17. In practical terms, the extinction of leatherback turtle in Malaysia. See [855].
  18. Sustainable forestry program. See [853].
  19. Congestion tax in Kuala Lumpur in August. It came back in December after the Kuala Lumpur mayor made a comment on it. This is a progressive policy but the public transportation system must be improved first. See [854].
  20. Growing rhinoceros population in Borneo. See [879].

That is a compilation of issues that started between January and some time in September 2006, inclusively. But of course, a year does not end in September and so, the complication continues.

  1. El Niño is officially back in September. See [883] and [886].
  2. The hunt for a killer crocodile in October. The act of revenge turn for the worse and became a merciless culling of crocodiles. The effort was criticized by greens and the culling immediately stopped in October. See [896].
  3. Temporary ban lift on commercial usage of paraquat. Something smell fishy. See [897].
  4. Legalization of turtle eggs collection by Terengganu state government in October. See [912].
  5. 300MV coal power plant in Sabah, as reported in November. See [975].
  6. New Orleans of Malaysia. See [1018].
  7. And perhaps, finally, after all these years, climate change. See [1017].

Will 2007 be a better year? Will the haze return?

Stay alive and find out next year.

Categories
Economics

[1020] Of flood, aid and economics

While relief effort is underway amid criticism, the government announced yesterday that flood victims are to get monetary aid:

Fair use. The Star. December 24 2006. Scanned by Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams.

Between food or other typical aid — henceforth, I shall refer to as commodity — and cash, which actually is the best to offer?

First, assume that there’s a constant amount of amount of cash and commodity for aid throughout this blog entry.

In circumstances where commodity supply is relatively stable, aid in cash might be the best. The reason is, every person has his or her (for simplicity’s sake, let me use the pronoun “he”. For all the feminists out there, I still love you guys! Or rather, girls) own preference. A person most of the time knows what he wants or needs the best. In economics, a person’s well-being could be measured by utility function. A utility function according to Wikipedia is “a measure of the relative happiness or satisfaction (gratification) gained by consuming different bundles of goods and services“. While utility is a basic concept in economics, it’s something hard to measure by a third person and usually, the person himself knows his utility own function the best. Through the person’s own preference, he, assuming rationality and complete information, will maximize his own consumption under relevant constrictions accordingly.

In emergency where shortage is widespread however, cash aid might not be the better mean of relieving victims of any disaster. This is especially so if the cash value isn’t large enough to purchase sufficient food and other necessary survival materials such as blanket, clothes, etc. During severe shortage period, prices will be higher than during peaceful times and with a specific amount of cash, a person will be able to buy less amount of food and other things that matter vis-a-vis during stable time.

A commodity-type aid is superior to cash-type aid if and only if the cash value of commodities is greater than cash value. Cash-type aid is superior to commodity-type aid if and only if the value of cash is greater than the value of the commodities. In short, the superiority order of the two kinds of aid depends on the value of the an aid relative to the other.

It must be noted that this comparison ignores the fact that monetary aid has considerably less logistical problem attached to it compared to the other aid type.

Regardless the two scenarios, an aid beneficiary could achieve higher welfare given any aid endowment if the beneficiary could trade with, of course, other people.