Categories
Economics

[3007] Finance would be the Dutch disease in a 14-state Malaysia

It is August coming into September. It is a month of feverish nationalism across Indonesia, Malaysia and Singapore. For the latter two, history is so intertwined that it is almost impossible to celebrate each other national day (days in case of Malaysia) independently and without dishing out minor insults across the Causeway. Over BFM just the other day, the hosts and guests were talking out loud how grateful they were to be Malaysians because of the food… which is better than Singapore’s. Some Singaporeans regularly express how grateful that Singapore is no longer part of Malaysia.

Beyond these banters, there are discussions of what-if. What if Singapore were still the 14th state of Malaysia? Would Malaysia be more prosperous than it is now?

I am in the opinion that the separation is for the best. A what-if Malaysia with Singapore in it would likely be worse for both parties: both Malaysia and Singapore would not be as prosperous as they are now. Both would pull each other back.

From an economic standpoint, the what-if Malaysia would be a Malaysia suffering from a kind of Dutch disease. We are accustomed to the Dutch disease through by overreliance on petroleum. But the Dutch disease can really be generalized into a sector that gobbles up so much resources that it raises cost across the economy, which in turn causes other sectors—especially manufacturing—to be uncompetitive.

In our what-if scenario, that sector would be finance (on top of petroleum).[0]

A strong and big financial sector works in the usual Dutch disease way: higher-than-average wages, which sucks talent away from other sectors. It would also suck other resources and reallocate capital towards short-term profitability instead of enabling greater investment that things like manufacturing usually need.

The well-being of the financial sector does not necessarily align with that of the economy (and within the context of industrialization, manufacturing). In How Asia Works, author Joe Studwell suggests that the financial sector must be put on a short leash to make industrialization works. In clearer terms, that means forcing banks to lend cheaply to manufacturers and having the financial sector bears more risks that it is willing to shoulder. There are other ways to counterbalance the influence of finance but an influential financial sector will make that harder if not impossible to do.

Finance was and is a big part of the Singaporean economy. While it is difficult to obtain clear data from the mid-20th century, as far as reliable and comparable records are concerned, financial services as a share of GDP in Singapore has been higher than it is in Malaysia since 1980.

Some rights reserved. By Hafiz Noor Shams.

The trend possibly began much earlier if we consider Singapore’s role as the financial and trading hub of colonial Malaya: the 1960s Singapore was not the swampy kampong some would claim it to be. In 1905, Singapore already operated a network of electric trams, which is shown below (in fact, Singapore had had steam trams as early as the 1880s):[1]

Koh Seow Chuan Collection, courtesy of National Archives of Singapore

So, if Singapore was still a Malaysian state and the growing finance GDP share trend held up as it did in the 1980s and all the way to the 2020s, I would think other sectors would be competing in a losing battle for resources. This is also part of the reason (in the real world) why some Singaporean more industrial firms have been relocating to Johor: it is too expansive for more and more industries to operate on the island state.

Additionally, the difference in the make-up of the Singapore economy and that of the Peninsula, and even more of the Bornean states, means economic interest and policy would diverge in a world where Singapore remains as a member state. In 1966, Singapore’s GNI per capita was already almost twice as large than that of Malaysia’s.

A concrete example of diverging interest could be seen from 1963 until 1965, there was major disagreement between Kuala Lumpur and Singapore over developmental funding: KL wanted Singapore to contribute more to support development not just in the Peninsula but also in Sabah and Sarawak, while Singapore thought it was being bullied into doing so. In fact, financial disagreement and questions regarding customs union between the federal Finance Minister Tan Siew Sin and Singapore’s Finance Minister Goh Keng Swee over the financial arrangement between Singapore and the Federation had played a role in the separation.

The divergence in policy could also be rationalized through monetary policy. The different stages of development between the member states means each component would need different policy treatment. The Peninsula, Sabah and Sarawak in the 1960s would likely need looser monetary policy relative to Singapore. A monetary authority trying to juggle the needs of such diverse economies would have a headache. Imagine the European Central Bank during the European debt crisis, where they had to satisfy the inflation-phobic German authorities while trying to save the Greece and other southern European economies. European authorities in the end resorted to painful internal devaluation for the already troubled economies.

Similarly for a what-if Malaysia, the benchmark rate would likely be too low for Singapore but to high for everybody else. In this case, the what-if Malaysia would grow slower than real-life Malaysia (making industrialization process harder than it should be) while a Singapore in Malaysia would likely face greater financial stabilities than real-world Singapore.

The fact that Singapore’s monetary policy regime today is so different from Malaysia’s just shows how difficult to run monetary policy in the what-if Malaysia.

And so, as far as development is concerned, separation was likely the best outcome we could hope for.

Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reservedHafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reservedHafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved

[0] — On Dutch disease, it is impossible to not mention oil & gas in real-world Malaysia. But I think Malaysia did well in managing petroleum resources due to other strong sectors such as agriculture and also due to strong effort to diversify and industrialize (that is industrialization in spite of petroleum but there are signs of petroleum crowding out other sectors there in Terengganu, Sabah and Sarawak). This is evident from the falling oil & gas since it peaked in the mid-1980s, in contrast to the rising prominence of finance in Singapore today. But the relevant point is, imagine having to deal with two sectors that would suck resources away from manufacturing. Would that Malaysia able to deal with two cost-rising sectors all at once? 

[1] — Electric tram at Collyer Quay, Singapore. Following the failure of steam trams in Singapore, electric trams were introduced in 1905 but eventually phased out by trolley buses in 1925-1927. [COLLYER QUAY, SINGAPORE. Seow Chuan Koh. National Archives Singapore. Extracted August 30 2025]

Categories
Books & printed materials

[2996] Reading The Flash Boys ten years after purchase

There was a time ages ago when I was enamored with the idea of finance. Just out of university, finance was the in thing. It was during this phase that I picked Michael Lewis’s Liar’s Poker. The author describes his bond trading experience in the late-1980s and early 1990s. He has written other books over the years: Moneyball and The Big Short among them. But it took me roughly 10 years after picking up Liar’s Poker to return to Lewis. Sometime in the mid-2010s, I bought The Flash Boys from Kinokuniya Kuala Lumpur.

But it would take me another 10 years to read and finish it. I have a bad habit of buying multiple books and later forgetting about them completely. On my shelves, I think between a fifth and a tenth of books there are unread. I am glad to say there is one more book out of the unread list.

The market has changed over the past 20-30 years and the contextual contrast between Liar’s Poker and The Flash Boys is huge. The former was set in a world where there were people on the trading floors taking bids and making offers for all kinds of financial instruments. By the 2010s, the floors were empty, the financial instruments had increased in complexity beyond the comprehension of most finance-people and computers had taken over buying and selling activities. Now, the most advanced markets are driven by algorithmic trading (before everything was labelled as AI), computing power and ultimately, super high-speed internet. That is the context of The Flash Boys: it is about high-frequency trading or HFT.

The greatest lesson I get from The Flash Boys is something that I already know: not all competition is good and for the financial markets, fragmentation (including multiple listings) largely creates room for inefficiencies.

The proliferation of stock exchanges has created unfair arbitrage opportunities for those with access to the most computing power and the fastest speed. That room for arbitrage exist in less than a tenth or even a hundredth of a microsecond, a window too small for a human to notice but a lifetime for computers. Here, having competing stock exchanges means having lags introduced into the whole financial system and that lag will be manipulated by high-frequency traders that thrive on delays too small for the human senses to detect. That manipulation comes in the form of frontrunning legitimate transactions which raises the cost a great majority in the market with HFT firms pocketing the additional charges.

This is just one example where competition is counterproductive to the market. For stock exchanges, we really do want to create a deep, one-location transparent market. Anything else creates information asymmetry.

Categories
Economics

[2702] Tighter lending requirement has its cost

I am unsure what to think about the recent move by Bank Negara Malaysia (BNM) to tighten lending on the non-bank side of the lending system. While the statistics in that sector is scary when compared to the banks, the non-bank sector does provide financial services to the low-income earners. The financial services provided here are not the fancy derivative kinds but rather, it is pretty much bread and butter things: giving out vanilla loans for a lot of stuff.

Without these institutions, these low income groups would probably lack access to financial services that they are enjoying now. That in some way has to mean improved welfare because these loans have to be used for something, either investment or consumption. And investment is simply deferred consumption anyway, which improves welfare eventually.

I have to admit that there are some problems with lending in non-bank financial institutions (NBFI). There is an explosion of personal financing granted by NBFI but in the grand scheme of things, it is small compared to the safer banking sector. Still, in the personal financing sector, more than 50% of loans were granted by NBFI according to BNM in its 2012 Financial Stability and Payment Systems Report. What makes it more worrying is that NBFI has looser requirements compared to the banks. Also, average amount for personal financing given out by NBFIs in 2012 was RM68,000 per person while most of the borrowers are civil servants who do not make much. (Still, impaired loans ratio in 2012 was extraordinarily low in spite of looser requirements. That has to do with a government deduction program. While the program is useful in keeping the ratio low, one wonders what the disposable income level of these borrowers is given that the borrowers are mostly government servants who do not earn too much).

Nevertheless, what would happen if these finance services were restricted? Or tightened?

Some might not go to the banks because they would likely be unqualified to obtain loans. If you cannot qualify for loans from NBFIs, what are the chances of getting loans from a sector with tighter regulation?

Others might not borrow at all, which is probably the ideal outcome for advocates of tighter lending requirements. For those who used the loose requirement to buy unnecessary stuff like buying an iPhone, a widescreen television or an expensive laptop to show-off, then the non-borrowing outcome is good.

But if they borrowed money for education, for food or essentially for smoothing their basic consumption, tightening will make them worse off. In their case, those loans give them a chance to build their life. These loans give them a leg up. Making it costlier for them sounds exceedingly cruel.

The worst outcome is probably if they go to the shadowy part of the economy and that quite possibly means going to the loan sharks. Having borrowers migrating to the least regulated (or even unregulated) sector of the economy cannot be considered a success of regulation. Protection in the underground economy is not as robust in the ”upper ground” economy. There is no bankruptcy law there. Here, not only one increases the systemic risk rather than reducing it through regulation, there will like be human cost — that is costlier than being condemned to bankruptcy — by becoming victims of crime.

That said, the restrictions by BNM are not drastic and those regulations, while it may reduce lending by NBFI, it is unlikely to cause mass exodus from NBFI to elsewhere. So, it is hard to imagine if BNM’s move increases systemic risk at all.

Yet, a small group of individuals will probably do just that and this group may be worse off.

Here is the point I want to stress. There is human cost to the tightening and that has been ignored while the mass media praises the tightening.

Categories
Economics Personal Politics & government

[2572] The bitterness of a financial conservative

I handle my finances conservatively. I spend very little for someone my age and my profile. In fact, I impose a sort of limit on my spending. I am conscious of it and get mildly nervous if my total spending grows too fast even when I can more than afford it.

I probably do buy too much insurance and I do save or invest a large part of my earnings. My credit card service provider probably hates me for having to finance me without getting the chance to charge me interest too often too much.

I can afford to save a lot partly because I do not have too many financial responsibilities.

The other factor behind my saving habit has a lot to do with my upbringing and education.

As a very young school kid, I never really needed to spend too much. Canteen food was clearly subsidized. I rarely asked my parents for expensive items.

The more important thing was that my parents did not give me a generous allowance when I was in primary school. My pocket money was very little. Not that I needed too much anyway but at that age, the limited pocket money effectively curbed any spending impulse I might have then. I was always mindful of my limits. It trained me to be financially prudent.

The same was true as I attended a boarding school in Kuala Kangsar; I rarely had expensive lunches or dinners. Meals were again subsidized and there was rarely a need to spend lavishly in a small rural royal town in Perak. While my allowance did increase, it was definitely less than that of my more well-off peers. I lived spartanly then. This continued during my undergraduate years in America. Formal lessons in economics further solidified my attitude towards personal finance.

During my time living abroad, I did learn to enjoy the finer things in life, but I rarely, if ever, overspent. I rarely overspend still.

So, I can say with certainty that I live by the morality of a financial conservative very strictly.

I think I can say without too much pretension that I am an economist. I understand the various reasons for fiscal deficits. Some of the causes for deficit are justifiable, and some are not. I do understand how the government is not a household in a way that the government can do certain things beyond typical household economics, the point which many defenders of the roles of government in society rush to in deflecting criticism against many facets of government spending. After six years of education in economics, I do not think I need too much schooling in that matter excessively.

Rather, put the economics aside and understand the psychology instead. Understand the worldview of a financially conservative taxpayer.

The state of federal government finance does not impress a person like me. Deep inside, I do feel something along the lines of ”if I can do it, why can’t Putrajaya?” It is a dismissive attitude towards the federal government. It is a damning judgment against a failure to adhere to certain brands of secular morality.

It is a kind of sentiment that is almost always in the background. It is the ever-present demand for financial discipline. Putrajaya violates this conservative morality so blatantly. Each violation accumulates further moral condemnation.

What further justifies the dismissive attitude is the inevitability that the indiscipline — add in the irresponsible economic populism that has happened throughout the year and earlier — will one day, one way or another, result in higher tax on the conservative, and everybody else, sooner or later. Whether I like it or not, I, will have to finance the fiscal indiscipline of Putrajaya.

That fuels my bitterness towards Putrajaya.

Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved
First published in The Malaysian Insider on July 26 2012.

Categories
Economics

[2403] The world has gone crazy

“…Treasuries have become a form of insurance against their own downgrade.” [Chris Reese. Bonds climb with safety buying as stocks dip. Reuters. July 26 2011]