Categories
Economics Politics & government

[2991] Malaysia’s 5G network: the search for the second-best solution has gone awry

Malaysia’s 5G policy is rife with unnecessary controversies. We could have a plain vanilla rollout plan but the power that be likes it complicated and here we are now. Perhaps, this is the hallmark of the Pakatan Harapan government: the more complicated it is, the better.

That vanilla rollout plan—very likely the best solution available—was this: auction the 5G spectrum to the highest telco bidders with the sufficient competencies and then let the winners carry out the necessary investment needed to roll out the 5G service. Malaysia has done this before with its 4G technology and that model worked reasonably well.

The ‘best’ here is qualified: it is from the government’s point of view. And the vanilla plan is a simple, transparent and a proven process. It provides the government with billions of additional revenue that Putrajaya needs for various pressing public purposes. While consumers will bear this cost in the form of high telecommunication fees, the market-based approach will allow the government to reallocate resources from high profitability private sector to the public sector (like healthcare, education and/or even defense that are in dire need of funding).

However, the market-based approach ignores a number of concerns that might be valid. Some concerns are redundant infrastructure/investment, slow rural rollout, vertical integration among the telcos, and higher cost to the consumers. Expanding these points briefly:

  • Redundant infrastructure: there is an argument that 5G and overall telco infrastructure are a natural monopoly: it is cheaper (and more efficient) to build a comprehensive infrastructure instead of multiple redundant networks with holes in the coverage (yes, there are cases when competition is inefficient). This argument goes hand-in-hand with economies of scale to be had with one giant infrastructure instead of having multiple networks.
  • Slow rural rollout: telcos had rolled out 4G technology slowly in the past by focusing on urban areas and delaying investment in the countryside. This is understandable because telcos have to get their returns fast and the cities are the gold mines. Investing on the countryside came much later because the returns here lower compared to the cities. I personally find this unconvincing because 5G technology (as far as I understand it… but I am happy to be corrected) is not meant for industrial and commercial uses. 4G should be able to cater to typical consumer usage.
  • Vertical integration: Here, the concern is telcos will enjoy vertical integration (the public is used to the idea of horizontal monopoly, but different kinds of monopoly exist), which is a control over a swath of telco value chain. This kind of control will allow telcos to enjoy much higher pricing/market power (basically, higher profit margin) versus a model without such integration.
  • Higher cost to end-consumers: The auction cost borne by telcos, their redundant investment cost and the effects of vertical integration will be passed to consumers. A telco price war could mitigate some of these problems but after controlling for that and other pricing regulations, telecommunication fees here will likely the highest compared to other models that exist out there.

I have summarized these points (and more) in a table below, taking into account how it affects 3 relevant parties: the government, the telcos and consumers.

Summary of 3 5G models in Malaysia with 3-party evaluation

These concerns are among the top reasons behind the search for the second-best solution in the late 2010s. That second-best solution in the end morphed into the single wholesale network that Digital Nasional Berhad is. Under the SWN setup, there are no auction while infrastructure investment cost are pooled by all (participating) telcos. Meanwhile, the government via DNB will regulate a 5G rollout plan more tightly so that rural locations do not get left behind. In summary, we have a single infrastructure, theoretically faster rural rollout and lower cost to consumers relative to the market-based option. Given this setup, it is appropriate to call this as a consumer welfare-maximizing model (line #2 in the table above).

Not everybody is happy with the best solution (hence, the search for the second-best): consumers and politicians who regularly play the political of living costs do not like it because it is costly. And Pakatan Harapan tends to play the politics of living costs by too much, as I have argued before. That politics affected the government of the day.

And yes, not everybody is happy with the second-best solution: telcos do not like it because they do not get vertical integration—to put it differently, they do not get to control the infrastructure. Instead, they get is a shared infrastructure with the government having a stake in it. All this points to lower profitability relative to the market-based approach.

However, awkwardly, the government is unhappy with the best and the second-best solution (for reasons I will not go into but which highlights the fact that there are more than 3 parties involved). And they have decided to deviate away from the two models. But instead of instituting improvements, the government appears to be taking the worst aspects of the first two models (see line #3 in the table). For the government, they get no auction revenue and weaker control over 5G infrastructure. The only real winners in the deviated model are the telcos since they do not face auction cost, they get full control over their networks and eventually, consumers will have cough out money for all that. This is ironic given how close the politics of living cost is to Pakatan Harapan.

Another point behind the deviation is the undermining of the second-best approach. The current policy adopted by the government effectively is dismantling the SWN and encouraging telcos to do individual and redundant networks. Because of the way the SWN/DNB works, telcos can pull out of it and join the second network. There are even talks for the third network and it is not hard to imagine almost telcos will have their own network if things go as it is. The fragmentation will present a challenge to profitability (or even viability) of the SWN model: individual telcos will only invest in profitable (largely urban) areas while DNB will be forced to invest in non-profitable (largely rural) locations, which will guarantee the failure of the SWN model.

The logical end to the current policy is as outlined in the line #3 in the table: the negative effects of market-based approach but without its benefits for the government and consumers, together with the negative effects of the second-best solution without its benefits for the government and consumers. To reiterate, the winners will be the telcos.

Winners and losers of the current Malaysia 5G policy.

Looking back, the search for the second-best approach was unwise, especially when the best approach was simple, transparent and a proven successful process. Opening the door to the next best solution has now led us to the worst of solutions. That search has now gone awry, leaving a complicated inefficient set of telecommunication policies.

Categories
Books & printed materials Politics & government Science & technology

[2983] Reading Chip War and some questions for Malaysia

I had expected it to be a technical reading but I was pleasantly surprised at the ease I read through Chris Miller’s Chip War: The Fight for the World’s Most Critical Technology. It is a 400-page book published back in 2022 at a time when chip availability was still a big problem that caused delays in delivery of everything that had semiconductors in it. Those goods included small electronics like cell phones and gaming consoles as well as large items such as cars. I had to wait for almost two years for the delivery of a new car from Japan. Even as the semiconductor market conditions improved by 2023, the issues discussed by Miller in his book remain relevant as the China-US tech war heats up further and as the use of AI among the public spreads.

For most parts, Chip War goes through the history of semiconductors and it is less so about contemporary contest between China and US. In this sense, I feel the title is a slight misnomer. When I first thought of the book title, I had imagined a little bit of reading notes from my work place: supply chain, industry interlinkages, international trade, policies, tariffs, war. While the author discusses these topics, they are all subsumed under the historical narrative that covered industry development during World War II and right up to the present day. And the historical narrative, in many ways, is written around multiple personalities (scientists, engineers, military men and politicians) who played (and still play) a role in the development of semiconductors. Contemporary issues are covered in a few chapters close to the end.

The author does provide brief technical description for things like early transistors, modern chips, and advanced equipment needed to make those chips. But that does not affect the readability of the book negatively, which is good thing. It is just not that technical. Some may find the non-technicality as a negative, since more than one engineer in multiple reviews have criticized Miller for oversimplifying various processes.

The United States is the main focus of the book, given its centrality in developing and the marketing semiconductors. Several other countries are mentioned extensively too. Soviet Union/Russia for its failure. Taiwan, South Korea and Japan for their successes. And China for being the new kid on the block and how the country is challenging US technological supremacy in a way the Soviet Union never could.

Malaysia has two or three mentions throughout the book, as the country plays major roles in testing and packaging of semiconductors. Those roles are not as sexy as designing or fabricating chips, but it is still essential in keeping the industry running.

Here, I want to touch something discussed in the book that has a direct impact on a specific Malaysian policy: the development of Malaysia’s 5G infrastructure within the context of China-US tech war.

Malaysia through its state-owned entreprise Digital National Berhad (DNB) is building the country’s 5G network with equipment and expertise supplied primarily by Ericsson. The selection of Ericsson is not without controversy, with the other contender being Huawei of China. The current government under Pakatan Harapan however appears unhappy with the DNB-Ericsson arrangement and has hinted that Malaysia should have a second network built by Huawei.

Of relevance here is that Huawei has come under strict restrictions imposed by the US, restrictions which have deprived the company from the latest chips needed to run 5G network. This has forced China to hasten the development of its own indigenous chip industry and indeed since 2020 when the US first tightened export controls on Huawei, the company and the general Chinese semiconductor industry have made progress in advancing its own chip design and manufacturing capability. Yet China is behind that of the US and its allies in terms chip technology. These allies include Taiwan that run the world’s most advanced chip manufacturing facilities (TSMC’s), and the Netherlands that makes the world’s most advanced chipmaking machinery (ASML’s). China is now able to design and manufacture 5nm chips (as of 2023?) but struggles to close the gap with 2nm chips that US-centric supply chain is now focusing on.

In more general terms, China might be 3-5 years behind the US chip technology. The 3-5 years gap might sound small, but for an industry governed by Moore’s Law, it is not something someone could shrug off.

Under these conditions, my question is, would it make sense to turn to Huawei for Malaysia’s 5G infrastructure (assuming building a second 5G network makes sense at all)?

From the way Miller described it in Chip War, Huawei faces difficulties in securing advanced chips needed for 5G equipment, unlike Ericsson.

And if Malaysia does get a second 5G network to be built by Huawei, would that 5G infrastructure be inferior to the first one due to restrictions faced by Huawei ?

Or is Chinese chip technology, wherever it is on the trailing edge, good enough for Malaysian purposes?

From Malaysian perspective, this does not sound like a geopolitical concern (Sinophobia?) that some in government make it out to be. Rather, it is a practical technological concern.