Categories
Economics

[2294] Of favoring the fat over the fit

The prime minister has said it so many times. His administration wants to turn Malaysia into a high-income country.  One of several initiatives that the administration believes can help in that direction is the introduction of minimum wage through the establishment of the National Wage Council. In promoting its supposedly market-friendly and market-driven policy, the federal government embarks on central planning without even flinching at the contradiction. For others, they will do more than flinch because as with any effort at central planning, there are side effects. One of them is the creation of an uncompetitive market.

In the free market, some firms have more market power than others do. That is inevitable due to various factors that are only too natural. Some are just larger than others are and they may have better access to resources and may be able make use of it more efficiently than others do, thus allowing them to sustain their prominence in the market.

That, however, does not prevent smaller firms from competing against their larger counterparts in the same industry successfully. There is enough flexibility in the free market to enable smaller firms to succeed. That flexibility creates free competition and that competition in the free market exacts punishment on mistakes made by anybody, even by larger firms. It gives others the opportunity to rise up.

This competitive force may no longer be true if the wage council dictates wages. The focus here is not the minimum wage itself but rather, the mechanism at which the council dictates the wage.

Consider the possible composition of the wage council. For it to be truly representative, it has to have all stakeholders in the labor market represented. This includes firms of all size and industries. There will be representatives from the labor unions and the government as well.

Consider now the interest of each side given an industry. The government wants to turn Malaysia into a high-income nation and believes the introduction of minimum wage can help. The labor unions want higher wage for its members and are strong advocates of minimum wage. The larger firms do not like competition and can afford higher wages. Finally, the smaller firms do not like competition as well but unlike the larger ones, they cannot afford to pay the kind of wages that the larger firms usually can.

One can see that at least one aspect of interest of the government, the labor unions and large firms coincides and then competes directly against the interest of small firms. Given this setup with the wage council, smaller firms are likely to lose out.

What begins as a problem of low wages or wage stagnation — what has been the rationale for the proposed formation of the wage council and the introduction of minimum wage in Malaysia — that is partly caused by unequal bargaining power between employers and employees is transformed into something else. It turns one problem into another.

While it attenuates the difference between employers and employees, the council amplifies the bargaining power differential between firms. The incentive mechanism of the free market is tweaked, or rather mangled, to give more leeway to larger firms to make mistake and less for smaller ones.

To put the implication more starkly, the wage council encourages the creation as well as the continuance of monopolies in the market. It creates an uncompetitive market, on top of the inflexibility created by the minimum wage policy.

What makes this all the more unpalatable to those who actually believe in market-driven policy is that many pre-existing monopolies in Malaysia are government-linked companies while the smaller companies are likely to be privately held. And when the monopolies are not government-owned, many of these monopolies came to being not because they were competitive, but because of past government policies of lemon socialism that privatized profits but socialized losses.

The concern for lemon socialism and privately-owned monopolies aside, the dynamic of the wage council is stacked against privately-held companies in favor of larger as well as government-linked companies. The role of the state in the market increases with the establishment of the wage council.

This is an example of Najib administration’s supposedly market-driven policy.

Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved

First published in The Malaysian Insider on December 28 2010.

Categories
Economics

[2229] Of a huge decrease in labor participation rate

I just ran through the recently released Malaysian labor force participation rate for May 2010 and I find it odd to see a huge drop in the rate. I wonder what explains the drop. Why suddenly a lot of individuals decided not to look for jobs anymore in May?

Categories
Economics

[2024] Of stimulus may be hurting recovery

I am holding the view that the RM67 billion government spending-based fiscal stimulus as announced will not be helpful. The market will show a swing independently of spending.

The swing is already happening in spite the fact that government spending has been insignificant so far. Furthermore, the magnitude of government spending is pale in comparison to the drop of external demand. If there is to be any recovery, it will be driven by external demand, just as the recession has been caused by external demand. All this makes the government spending-based stimulus irrelevant.

Due to temporal issue between the effectiveness of the spending and market cycle, when proper recovery takes places, private firms will suffer from crowding out effect since the stimulus is financed through local sources. Interest will have to go up higher when compared to a situation where there the size of government spending is absent.

Well, I might be wrong. My position is too kind. There is a piece yesterday that may indicate that the stimulus is hurting recovery:

GEORGE TOWN: Penang’s electronics industry is facing a shortage of production workers after orders started to pick up early last month, according to a job outsourcing company.

The problem is compounded by local workers who prefer to enrol instead in the government’s retraining scheme where they are paid more, said Inter Resources Consulting Global Search (M) Sdn Bhd managing director Michael Heah.

He said locals were not keen to work long hours in factories for RM500 to RM600 a month, preferring the retraining scheme for unemployed graduates and retrenched workers where they were taught new skills and received a monthly allowance of between RM500 and RM800. [Penang electronics firms unable to cope with demand. The Star. July 2 2009]

Firms are actually competing — gasp! — with the stimulus package for labor, making them incapable of meeting demand in the short run.

How is that for a stimulus?

Worse:

Heah said the electronics industry started to recover last month with the semiconductor and consumer electronics sector stepping up their recruitment drive to get more locals to fill vacancies.

”To make matters worse, the intake of foreign workers has been frozen. We appeal to the Government to lift the freeze in the sector,” he said. [Penang electronics firms unable to cope with demand. The Star. July 2 2009]

Unless productive firms can find individuals that are not enrolled in the retraining program, they will need to raise wages.

I am a fan of raising wages only to accommodate inflation, to compensate improvement in productive for the labor factor of production or competition from firms for labor.

I see none of those here. That potential raise of wages may be caused by distortion created by the government, more than anything else.

Categories
Economics

[1976] Of it is just as crowded over there

Read the mainstream press and it is hard to miss that the Economic Planning Unit and the Ministry of Finance are trying to market a new economic model to replace old ones. I fear that this new model is misguided and will lead Malaysia down the wrong path.

Read the mainstream press and one will find that it is popular these days to state that Malaysia needs to go up the economic value chain. Almost always accompanying that is rhetoric calling for Malaysia to graduate from its addiction to low-wage, low-skilled workers which, by and large, refers to dependency on cheap foreign labor.

Policy-wise, this has been translated into restriction on recruitment of cheap foreign labor. As proof, an astronomical levy on recruitment of foreign workers was imposed as part of the second stimulus package.

In time of economic slowdown, that particular action does not make sense and luckily, the Najib administration understands this and has decided to postpone it indefinitely. But even without a slowdown, that is no way to move forward due to uncertainty of any country’s development path.

Nonetheless, it is true that Malaysia needs to move up the value chain. We have been benefiting massively from early adoption of a liberal economy but other recently liberalized economies like India and China are finally catching up with Malaysia, and at an amazing pace.

Rapid reduction of poverty and continuous registration of high economic growth are testaments of how fast these countries are catching up after abandoning flawed economic models that ignore the importance of private property as a basis of a society.

Not only are they catching up rapidly thanks to liberalization, with their overwhelmingly larger and cheaper supply of labor, they are crowding out Malaysia and its peers like Thailand and the Philippines from the low-wage, low-skilled and labor-intensive niche. Penang, for instance, is already seeing multinational corporations migrating out from the state to Vietnam and China. This trend occurs because, among other reasons, of the availability of cheaper and larger supply of labor.

From this perspective, Malaysia is indeed losing its competitiveness; Malaysia is unable to compete in a low-wage model. If Malaysia fails to react, challenges from these low-cost countries have the potential to wreak havoc on the Malaysian economy. Fearing being pushed to the margin in the global market, Malaysia seems to be left with nowhere to go but up in the value chain.

Going up does not automatically mean actively restricting recruitment of cheap foreign labor, though. Cheap foreign labor still has roles in the Malaysian economy, even as its importance continue to diminish and even as other countries are able to excel at low-wage, low-skilled industry better than Malaysia.

This point is all the more tenable since in the long run, price equalization will happen to bring some kind of equilibrium between Malaysia and other competing countries.

The new equilibrium for low-wage, low skilled industry — perhaps especially for manufacturing — for Malaysia may be below its current level but the requirement for such industry will still exist since it provides goods or services which are hard if not impossible to trade. Somebody will have to do it.

Restriction on recruitment of cheap foreign labor is doubly unhelpful if the locals themselves refuse to take up low-wage low-skilled jobs. The restriction will create upward pressure on prices which include wages, pushing up the cost of living unnecessarily high when access to a large source of cheap labor to stabilize prices is available in the region.

In an open economy, that pressure will attract cheap supply of labor to act as a counterbalance. If that source is unavailable locally at the right prices, it will come from abroad.

That is already happening in Malaysia and the same trend is observable in the United Kingdom, where Eastern Europeans are taking up low paying jobs which the locals are reluctant to do as cheaply as the immigrants are willing. The same is true in the United States but instead of Eastern Europeans, they are from Mexico or other parts of Latin America.

A restriction on foreign labor will prevent that from happening, forcing prices and wages to go up. I feel this point must be stressed and hence, I repeat, that will inevitably cause the cost of doing business to increase.

The upward pressure on wages has been suggested as a tool to attract talents into Malaysia as an effort to take Malaysia forward beyond low-wage low-skilled economy into the realm of new economy.

This, however, confuses an increase in nominal wealth with an increase in real wealth. What is the point of being paid higher wages when the cost of living goes up accordingly, or higher?

In other words, the restriction which drives nominal wages up really makes no difference in real terms.

It must be noted that any increase in real wealth is largely due to productivity. This is not a mere opinion. Rather, it is an economic fact.

If one is less willing to believe mainstream economic theory due to the unfavorable popular reputation that economists currently suffer, then do refer to any econometric model on the matter; the correlation is strong and the causal relationship is enticing. Any effort at moving up the value chain must take this into account.

By moving up the value chain, it inevitably means greater application of science and innovation to increase productivity. A highly educated workforce will be required if the economy is to enjoy higher productivity.

In light of this, the question is not whether our addiction to cheap labor is a barrier to take the economy to a higher plane.

Instead, the questions that demand answers are: does Malaysia have a highly educated workforce; does Malaysia have the talents to fulfill the prerequisite of a high-value economy?

With a minority of its population holding a graduate degree and with an education system that seeks to brainwash its students rather than encourage critical thinking, it is a stretch to answer the questions in the positive.

That, by no means, is a reason to throw in the towel but it can help to refocus our energy from wrongfully vilifying low-skilled foreign labor to educating Malaysians better.

What is needed is an education system that demands the biggest effort from all. Schools, colleges and universities need to be liberalized to encourage development of competitive, thinking and open minded workforce, not yet more groups to be goaded for political purposes.

While these workforce is being developed, foreign talents should be welcomed and even offered citizenship.

Furthermore, just as the argument that low-cost giants are crowding Malaysia out from the low-wage, low-skilled niche, what actually guarantees that Malaysia can break into the high-value, high-skilled niche already filled with countries that with highly educated workforce?

Somehow, the rhetoric and the central planning action by the government which lead to curbs on foreign labor seems to suggest there is heavy competition in low-skilled industry but not in high-skilled industry.

”It’s crowded here, let’s move over there. Simple.” Well, it is not. While the pay off from a high-value economy is huge, it is naïve to think that there will be no competition.

Just imagine how much resources will be required to reverse the serious brain drain Malaysia has been experiencing for so long. Malaysia is way behind the curve in competition for talents. Compounding the issue is unfair practices by the government that make certain groups of Malaysia unappreciated.

If restriction of employment of cheap foreign labor is used as a stick to force Malaysia up the value chain, the danger is that Malaysia might fail to break into the high-skill niche and then finding itself with a largely dismantled low-skill industry.

With a serious lack of talent in the local economy, Malaysia might not only find itself entrenched in the middle-income trap, it might fall behind in comparison with its peers.

Unnecessary hostile position against cheap foreign labor might cause Malaysia to not have a fallback position if there is an error of judgment.

It is therefore, in my humble opinion, imperative that we ensure the ledge on the other side of the gully is properly secured before we make the jump across rather than chipping off the ledge we are still on. If we find ourselves in mid air only to realize that the ledge on the other side cannot support us, the next place we will be is at the bottom of the gully.

Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved Mohd Hafiz Noor Shams. Some rights reserved

First published in The Malaysian Insider on May 4 2009.

Categories
Economics Society

[1440] Of pre-arranged marriage may hurt the labor market

Even during these days, they are those that advocates arranged marriage. The idea is obsolete and belongs to the stone age for so many reasons and therefore, there are many reasons and more to frown at arranged marriage. The Marginal Revolution stumbled upon one reason why hands of parents are inferior to marriage arranged by the invincible hand, specific to India:

“Arranged” marriages, characterized by strong parental control over mate choice, are the norm in India, although there is a steady transition towards autonomous ”love” marriages, especially within the urban middle class. I construct a novel dataset by surveying 6,030 parents and adult children in Mumbai, India, to study selection into arranged marriage and its effects on spouse choice. I consider the choice between an arranged and a love marriage as the outcome of bargaining between parents and children, when agents have different preferences for spouse attributes. I find that stronger financial and kinship ties between parents and sons increase the likelihood of an arranged marriage. Furthermore, when parents are involved in mate choice, sons are significantly less likely to marry college-educated women and women engaged in the labor force, after controlling for individual and family characteristics. I show that these effects are driven, at least in part, by parental preferences and cannot be entirely attributed to correlation between arranged marriages and unobserved characteristics or preferences. These results suggest that lowering the incentive for parental control in mate choice may improve investments in women’s human capital in India. [Divya Mathur. What’s Love Got To Do With It? Parental Involvement and Spouse Choice in Urban India. November 7 2007]